logo

52 pages 1 hour read

Daron Acemoglu, James A. Robinson

Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty

Nonfiction | Book | Adult | Published in 2012

A modern alternative to SparkNotes and CliffsNotes, SuperSummary offers high-quality Study Guides with detailed chapter summaries and analysis of major themes, characters, and more.

Chapters 7-9Chapter Summaries & Analyses

Chapter 7 Summary: “The Turning Point”

Chapter 7 highlights the critical developments in England that set the stage for the Industrial Revolution, illustrating how the interplay between political power, economic interests, and technological innovation shaped the path to modern economic growth.

The chapter begins with the story of William Lee, who invented a knitting machine in 1589, only to have his request for a patent denied by both Queen Elizabeth I and James I. The monarchs feared the political implications of such a technology, as it threatened to make many workers redundant. This story exemplifies the concept of “creative destruction,” where new technologies disrupt existing economic and social structures. The resistance of elites and rulers to such innovations often stifled technological progress and economic growth.

The narrative then shifts to the 17th century, highlighting the pivotal role of the Glorious Revolution of 1688 in England. This revolution marked a shift from extractive to inclusive political institutions, laying the groundwork for economic transformation. Unlike previous conflicts that merely replaced one ruling elite with another, the Glorious Revolution led to a broad coalition of interests, including merchants, industrialists, and other social groups, who collectively demanded more pluralistic political institutions. This new political landscape fostered an environment where property rights were more secure, financial markets improved, and monopolies in foreign trade were undermined, encouraging economic innovation and growth.

Political conflict played an important role in shaping these institutional changes. The Magna Carta and the establishment of the first elected Parliament in 1265 gradually constrained the monarchy’s power and expanded the representation of diverse interests. These developments, coupled with the growth of trade and the emergence of new merchant classes, created a powerful coalition against the absolutist ambitions of the Stuart monarchs.

The expansion of trade, particularly in the Atlantic, played a critical role in this process. The inability of the Tudor and Stuart monarchs to monopolize this trade led to the rise of a class of merchants and businessmen who opposed absolutism and demanded different economic institutions. This emerging class was crucial in opposing James II and supporting the Glorious Revolution.

After the Glorious Revolution, the Parliament took control of state policy, which led to changes in economic institutions and government policies. This included reforms in property rights, taxation, finance, and the protection of domestic industries. The Glorious Revolution also continued the process of political centralization, which increased the state’s effectiveness and resource mobilization.

The culmination of these changes was the Industrial Revolution, driven by innovations in textile production, transportation, and metallurgy. Pioneers like James Watt and Richard Arkwright, who might have been stifled under previous regimes, now thrived in a more inclusive institutional environment. The revolution in cotton textiles and the advent of the factory system were particularly transformative.

The Industrial Revolution began in England due to the unique set of inclusive economic institutions established after the Glorious Revolution, which were themselves a product of the inclusive political institutions that emerged from the complex interplay of historical events, institutional drift, and critical junctures. The broad coalition against absolutism and the shift toward pluralism were decisive in creating an environment conducive to economic innovation and growth.

Chapter 8 Summary: “Not on Our Turf: Barriers to Development”

Chapter 8 explores the resistance to the spread of industry and innovation in various absolutist and politically fragmented societies during the critical juncture created by the Industrial Revolution. The chapter begins with the story of the Ottoman Empire’s resistance to the printing press, highlighting how Sultan Bayezid II in 1485 forbade printing in Arabic due to concerns about the spread of subversive ideas that might threaten the existing political and social order. This resistance to the printing press had consequences for literacy, education, and economic success in the Ottoman Empire.

The chapter then discuss the broader impacts of absolutism and the lack of political centralization on industrialization, using examples from various countries. In Russia and Austria-Hungary, the absolutist regimes did not encourage economic progress and actively blocked the spread of industry and new technologies. Their opposition to innovation was driven by fear of the creative destruction that accompanies economic change and by their desire to maintain the status quo.

By contrast, the lack of political centralization in Somalia prevented the development of even the most basic security of property rights, making it impossible for the society to benefit from the Industrial Revolution. The absence of a centralized state meant that Somali society remained engaged in internal conflicts and feuding, further entrenching economic decline.

For absolutist Spain, the discovery of precious metals in the Americas paradoxically contributed to the empire’s economic decline. This decline was exacerbated by the expropriation of Jewish and Morisco populations and the imposition of extractive economic institutions. Unlike England, which embraced pluralistic political institutions and commercial expansion, Spain’s absolutist monarchy and rigid economic controls stifled innovation and participation in international trade. This divergence in institutional paths between Spain and England is presented as a pivotal factor in their contrasting economic fortunes and responses to the Industrial Revolution.

Both absolutism and the lack of state centralization served as barriers to the adoption of new technologies and economic development during the Industrial Revolution. These factors prevented many societies from taking advantage of the opportunities presented by this critical juncture, leading to enduring economic decline.

Chapter 9 Summary: “Reversing Development”

Chapter 9 examines how European colonialism and expansion negatively impacted economic and political development in various regions. The chapter begins with the story of the Moluccan Archipelago in Indonesia, famous for its spices. Initially, these islands engaged in prosperous trade with Asian and Middle Eastern countries. However, European powers, particularly the Portuguese and later the Dutch, sought to monopolize the lucrative spice trade. The Dutch East India Company played a pivotal role in this endeavor, employing violence and coercion to establish control over spice production. Their monopolization had socioeconomic consequences for the local population.

The Dutch’s strategies in the Moluccas were replicated across Southeast Asia, effectively reversing the region’s economic growth and development. Many states retreated from trade and turned inward due to the Dutch threat. For example, Banten in Java destroyed its pepper trees to avoid Dutch aggression, and the ruler of Maguindanao in the Philippines ceased growing nutmeg and cloves for similar reasons. This retreat led to de-urbanization and possibly a decline in population.

In Africa, the slave trade had profound and lasting impacts. European demand for enslaved people led to increased warfare in Africa, as captives were often sold into slavery. This demand for enslaved people not only resulted in demographic changes but also altered the social and political fabric of African societies. Many African states became more absolutist and focused on capturing and selling enslaved people. The abolition of the slave trade in the early 19th century by Britain and the United States did not immediately improve conditions in Africa. Instead, it led to the redeployment of enslaved people within Africa for labor in producing commodities for export.

The chapter also discusses the concept of the “dual economy” in the context of South Africa. It argues that the economic disparity between the modern, developed sector and the traditional, underdeveloped sector was not a natural or inevitable result of development. Instead, it was deliberately engineered by European settlers and the South African government. Policies such as the Natives Land Act of 1913 were designed to impoverish African farmers and create a cheap labor force for European-owned mines and agricultural enterprises. This act of disenfranchisement led to the stagnation and decline of the African economy.

Chapters 7-9 Analysis

Chapter 7 develops The Role of Institutions in Economic Development, focusing on England’s transition toward inclusive institutions. The Glorious Revolution of 1688 is portrayed as a critical juncture that shifted England from extractive to inclusive political institutions, laying the foundation for economic transformation. The Glorious Revolution also serves as an example of how political changes can catalyze economic transformation, foregrounding The Impact of Political Systems on National Prosperity. The chapter employs metaphor and analogy to expand on this theme, representing the revolution and its aftermath as a turning point not only for England but for the modern world. For instance, the story of William Lee’s knitting machine is not just a historical anecdote; it serves as a metaphor for the transformative force of creative destruction. Lee’s invention, facing resistance from the status quo, symbolizes the broader struggle between innovation and entrenched societal structures.

Chapter 8 likewise explores The Impact of Political Systems on National Prosperity, focusing on how political systems, particularly those resistant to change and innovation, can act as barriers to economic development. Like William Lee’s knitting machine in Chapter 7, the Ottoman Empire’s rejection of the printing press becomes an apt historical analogy. It highlights how rigid political structures can stifle economic progress, acting as a barrier to innovation and industrialization, and serves as a metaphor for the broader impacts of absolutism and political fragmentation on industrialization. Analogies and metaphors not only make complex economic theories more accessible but also emphasize the intricate interplay between political systems and economic development. Their inclusion enriches the narrative, making it not just an academic discourse but a story of economic evolution.

Chapter 9 examines The Historical Evolution of Economic and Political Structures, revealing how external forces such as colonialism can drastically alter the economic and political landscape of regions, often leading to the establishment of extractive institutions. The Dutch East India Company’s monopolization of the spice trade in the Moluccan Archipelago serves as an example of European colonial practices and their destructive effects on local economies:

The East India Company looted local wealth and took over, and perhaps even intensified, the extractive taxation institutions of the Mughal rulers of India. This expansion coincided with the massive contraction of the Indian textile industry, since, after all, there was no longer a market for these goods in Britain (273).

This quote highlights the destructive nature of colonialism, where the East India Company’s activities in India not only appropriated local wealth but also led to the decline of indigenous industries. It exemplifies the broader theme of how colonial powers often disrupted and suppressed local economies for their own gain, leaving a legacy of extractive institutions. The chapter also discusses the slave trade in Africa and the concept of the dual economy in South Africa, using these examples to illustrate the way colonial powers deliberately engineered economic disparities. The chapter’s synthesis of historical events and economic theory underscores its argument that external interventions can reverse the course of a region’s economic development.

These chapters focus on historical events and transformations that have impacted the development of countries. From the Glorious Revolution in England to the impact of colonialism in Asia and Africa, the authors present a narrative that weaves together historical incidents with their economic implications. Their analysis not only sheds light on the past but also offers insights into the present-day economic and political landscapes of nations around the world.

blurred text
blurred text
blurred text
blurred text